Wednesday, 3 December 2014

POLITICS OF REVENUE ALLOCATION IN NIGERIA: A RECONSIDERATION OF SOME CONTENDING ISSUES IKEJI, Chibueze C. Institute of Public Policy And Administration (IPPA) University Of Calabar, Nigeria




ABSTRACT


Whatever the theoretical and practical imperatives of federalism are, revenue allocation (livewire in authoritative value allocation or who gets what, when, how and where?) remains an object of intense politics and, unquestionably, a major source of inter-group or inter-regional antagonism. Nigeria is no exception to this rule. Politics, well-anchored possess the potential of balancing conflicting interests and resolving socio-economic and political contradictions in the society. How far have politics in Nigeria gone in resolving contradictions associated with revenue allocation? This paper identifies six major contradictions/challenges confronting revenue allocation practice and concomitant inter-governmental fiscal relations in Nigeria, name: Non-Correspondence Problem; Fiscal Autonomy and Independence; Who Owns the Golden Goose (Federal Government, States, Local Governments or Communities?); Federation Account and Derivation Fund; OilProducing Areas and the Derivation Principle; and Inter-governmental Fiscal Relations and the Economy. Upon analysis, the paper argues that the Nigerian State have not, and may well not be able to, resolve these nagging issues. The politically and economically fragile Nigerian state, operating in a highly unstable, fragile and geo-politically polarized society shows limited capacity to deal with these challenges. By this default, the paper argues, the promise of inventing development-promoting revenue sharing formula is lost in Nigeria. National progress is the ultimate casualty.

Keywords: Revenue allocation, federalism, Nigeria
 

INTRODUCTION


The question of an acceptable formula for revenue sharing among the component tiers of the Nigerian nation is one of the most protracted and controversial debates in the political and macroeconomic management of the economy. This debate has its foundations in the history and evolution of the Nigerian federation.

“Revenue allocation or the statutory distribution of revenue from the Federation Account among the different levels of government has been one of the most contentious and controversial issues in the nation’s political life. So contentious has the matter been that none of the formulae evolved at various times by a commission or by decree under different regimes since 1964 has gained general acceptability among the component units of the country. Indeed, the issue, like a recurring decimal, has painfully remained the first problem that nearly every incoming regime has had to grapple with since independence. In the process, as many as thirteen different attempts have been made in devising an acceptable revenue allocation formula, each of which is more remembered for the controversies it generated than issues settled” (Report of the Political Bureau, 1987:169).

A federal system of government often arises from the desire of the peoples to form a union without necessarily losing their identities. Federalism would, therefore, seem to provide an attractive system of government especially in the context of ethnic pluralism found in many African states. Federalism is generally accepted by many as necessary for managing the country’s ethnic diversity as reflected in the adage “unity in diversity”. Federalism in principle implies the construction of a system where consensus is reached between current demands of the union and the territorial diversity within an emerging society, by the creation of a single political system within which central and provincial governments are assigned coordinated authority in a manner defining both the legal or political limits of equality or subordinate functions (Agbu, 2004). The choice of federalism as the preferred system of government for Nigeria was not accidental. The eventual transformation of Nigeria into a federal state started in 1954 as a result of the 1953 Lyttleton constitution conference.
In a federal structure, adequate autonomy is given to each level of government to enable it perform its responsibility without frustration. Table 1 outlines the functions of the three tiers of government. This is the essence of fiscal federalism. Fiscal federalism refers to the scope and structure of the tiers of government responsibilities and functions as well as the allocation of resources among the tiers of government. Perhaps the most important issue of fiscal federalism is the revenue allocation formula, the sharing of national revenue among the various tiers of government (vertical revenue sharing) as well as the distribution of revenue among the state governments (that is, horizontal revenue allocation). The centralization of Nigeria’s fiscal federalism began with the report of the Dina Commission (1968) which argued that an appropriate revenue allocation system should result in a more equitable distribution of revenue among the states to achieve a balanced development of the federation.
Revenue allocation can be described as a method(s) of sharing the centrally generated revenue among the different tiers of government and how the amount allocated to a particular tier is shared among its components. Nigeria is a federal state – under the federal system of government, federation or centrally-generated revenue is shared among the three levels of government, namely; the federal government, the states and the local governments. The theory of revenue sharing in a federal state is that each level of government receives an allocation of financial resources tailored to their specific requirements as defined by the mandate of legislative competence, their actual situation and the statutory indices of calculation. In Nigeria, decisions as to what proportion of centrally-generated revenue that would be retained by the federal government, the proportion that will be shared among the state governments and the proportion that will go to the local government has always been a problem, due to the fact that there is no consensus of opinion as to what could be seen as an ideal formula. In the words of Obi (1998:262), “the issue of revenue allocation strikes at the very basis of existence of the Nigerian federation and the rules of entry and exit from the ruling class”.
The struggle for the control of the nation’s resources have also, to some extent been based on the regional cleavages. This, entwined with political conflict, has sometimes led to political manipulations and delineations with the aim of influencing wealth allocation. This has been especially so since 1958, revenue from oil gained prominence as the major source of revenue in the country. Along these lines, it has been suggested that: the setting up of three commissions on revenue allocation within a short period of twelve years is a manifestation of the instability that characterized the Nigerian polity. Between 1968 and 1980, income from petroleum constituted over 80 percent of federal revenue. The importance of the federal centre therefore increased proportionately. As a consequence of this major shift in revenue generation, a desperate struggle to win control of state power ensued since this control meant for all practical purposes, being all powerful and owning everything. Wantchekon (1999) conducted an empirical study that sought to establish that natural resource dependence and rentier economies generate authoritarian governments, very slow process of political reforms and socio-political instability.
The most recent development in the struggle for the control of oil resources in Nigeria is the recent Supreme Court action instituted by the federal government against the oil producing states with respect to the offshore/onshore oil dichotomy. The April 2002 decision of the Supreme Court to exclude the revenue derived from offshore drilling in the calculation of the revenue attributable to the oil producing states based on the derivation principle, has failed to resolve the controversy. “There arose a dispute between the federal government on the one hand and the eight littoral states of Akwa Ibom, Bayelsa, Cross River, Delta, Lagos, Ogun, Ondo and Rivers States on the other hand as to the Southern (or seaward) boundary of each of these states. The federal government contends that the southern (or seaward) boundary of each of these states is the low water mark of the land surface of such state…. [or] the seaward limit of inland waters within the state, as the state so requires. The federal government therefore, maintains that natural resources located within the Continental Shelf of Nigeria are federal government’s contentions. Each of the states claims that its territory extends beyond the low water mark onto the territorial water and even onto the continental shelf and the exclusive economic zone. They maintain that natural resources derived from both onshore and offshore are derivable from their respective territory and in respect thereof each is entitled to the “not less than 13 percent” allocation as provided in the proviso to subsection (2) of section 162 of the Constitution” (Judgement by the Supreme Court, 5 April 2002).
This persistent struggle for revenue has however the wide ranging effect on the sustainability of programs and reforms for the economic transformation of the entire Nigerian economy. This paper therefore, seeks to articulate and document what the divergent contending issues have been and argues that the focus on revenue sharing, as opposed to revenue generation and accountability in the utilization, is the primary cause of economic, social and political decay in the country.

PRINCIPLES OF FISCAL FEDERALISM


The principles that guide the implementation of intergovernmental fiscal relations include:
(a)               The Principle of Diversity: The federal system must have the ability to accommodate a large variety of diversities. Hence, the fiscal system must provide scope for variety and differences to supply national, regional and local public goods.
(b)               The Principle of Equivalence: Based on the geographical incidence of different public goods, allocative efficiency requires the equalization of locational advantages arising from inter-jurisdictional differences with a combination of taxes and public goods and services.
(c)               The Principle of Centralized Stabilization: This requires the use of fiscal instruments for achieving macroeconomic objectives of growth, stabilization and full employment by residents of different geopolitical units; this requirement controls for what is often referred to as “central city exploitation thesis”.
(d)               Minimum Provision of Essential Goods and Services: This ensures that fiscal federalism guarantees all citizens, irrespective of where they reside, the minimum provision of certain basic public goods and services.
(e)               Principle of Fiscal Equalization: In order to ensure a minimum level of public goods and services same degree of fiscal equalization is required. This is as a result of differences in resource endowment.
(f)                The Efficiency Principle: This principle implies that efficiency must be applied in the allocation of resources. In addition, each level of government should maximize its internal revenue earnings at minimum tax efforts.
(g)               The Principle of Derivation: The component units of a system should be able to control some of its own resources as they desire.
(h)               The Principle of Locational Neutrality: Interregional fiscal differences tend to influence location choices of individuals and firms. Based on different resource endowments, differences in tax capacity and effort, some decree of locational interference seems to be an inevitable cost of intergovernmental fiscal relations. Therefore, policy should focus on minimizing distortions due to some interference. Hence, differential taxes which create locational distortions should be avoided as much as practicable (Agiobenebo, 1999:43).
(i)                 The Principle of Centralized Redistribution: This principle states that the redistribution function of fiscal policy through progressive taxation and expenditure programmes should be centralized at the federal level. This seems consistent with the principle of locational mentality. That is, if the redistributive function is decentralized, it can result in distortions in location decisions.

It should be noted that the above principles are not mutually consistent. They are difficult to apply simultaneously. Therefore, tradeoffs are necessary in order to avoid conflicts. There is no doubt that the general principles of fiscal federalism appeared to have informed Nigeria’s attempt at intergovernmental fiscal relations. The different principles have been dictated by a combination of historical experiences, political, cultural and social factors. After almost forty years in search of a workable fiscal federalism, there still exist challenges which policymakers must address.

“It is an act of self-deception for anyone to argue that there is nothing wrong with the revenue formula. We have had basically two systems of revenue allocation in Nigeria. The first system which we practiced during the First Republic allowed the North to keep the proceeds from its groundnut and cotton, the West to keep the proceeds from its cocoa, and the East to keep the proceeds from coal and oil produce. Then we changed the system so that the federal government got its hands on the proceeds from onshore and offshore crude petroleum proceeds, and yet we don’t expect the minorities in the oil producing areas to perceive that is an injustice done to them. I have even heard some people turning history on its head by arguing that the country was developed on the proceeds of groundnut, cocoa and oil palm. Perhaps, [one could be correct] if you are arguing that the whole is the sum of its parts. But the oil producing minorities has a point that the rule of the revenue allocation game were changed to disfavour them (Professor Bolaji Akinyemi, COMET , June 6, 2001)”. 

It is against the backdrop of the preceding assertion, delivered by a Nigeria academic and a delegate to the National Political Reform Conference, that the complicated discussion regarding the revenue allocation formula at the National Political Reform Conference might be visualized. The South-South zone (in the imagined or putative division of Nigeria into six geopolitical zones) insists on this confabulation that in order to address past anomalies in the allocation scheme that it should be given 25% instead of 13% (or 17%) as a first step toward boosting the percentage to 50%. In spite of the empirical evidence to support the claims of the South-South at the confab, the north, as represented by some of its oligarchs argue against a change in the formula that would address the needs of the ethnic minorities whose territory houses the country’s bread winner – crude oil. The north argues for a 17% derivation for the oil producing area.

THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF OIL REVENUE ALLOCATION IN NIGERIA

Welfare economics and political theory are the two stands of theory which significantly guides revenue allocation. The main theme of the economic argument is the bridging of inequality gap. This gap exists because of unequal endowment of natural resources which result in an imbalance in the physical development of the communities. According to Oyediran and Olagunji (1984) higher spatial poverty in natural resource endowment increases the agitation for equality as a revenue allocation criterion. Fiscal policy is the deliberate use of revenue generating and spending machinery of the government to steer the economy in the desired direction. The major economic roles of government are resource allocation, income distribution and macroeconomic stabilization. Through fiscal activities, taxes are levied on economic activities in the regions with concentrated economic resources and some of the proceeds transferred to the scant resources region, in a way that will guarantee equitable distribution across sectors and geographical regions within a fiscal system. The centrally collected revenue across sectors shared such that horizontal fiscal disparities among localities and vertical imbalances among tiers of government are minimized (Akpan and Umodong, 2003:338).
Federalism provides a framework for solving the political problem of administration and the economic problem of resource distribution. In practice, sometimes, the optimization of administrative costs is an economic issue, where also the distribution of resources involves some political issues in determining the constitutional criteria for such allocation in such a way that will ensure equality and/or equity. An efficient distribution is that in which no section of the society is worse off, while making the other better off. However, Musgrave and Musgrave (1982) observe, that the problem of efficiency is beset with major measurement difficulties when the issue of redistribution is evaluated. This is because redistribution entails balancing of value with gains accruing from all parts of the society from fiscal operations. Akpan and Umodong (2003) observe that redistribution that can ensure equality will not guarantee efficiency, thus the question of balancing the inefficiency and equality in an acceptable way encompasses the use of economic and political means to induce compromise and agreement. This may involve the use of consultation approach to power balancing and the protection of rights. The use of the government revenue allocation principle to engender development in resource poor region is based on the theory of balanced growth, which emphasizes the need to provide the basic minimum developmental conditions (infrastructures) necessary for each region to rise above the low-level equilibrium trap and accumulate the preconditions for the take off. Planned development therefore calls for inter-regional transfer of resources through some fiscal processes.
Although the consumption of public goods increases the welfare of the beneficiary, the provision of public goods entails the transfer of resources from individuals to the public sector. Such transfers reduce the level of consumption of private goods on which the affected individuals could have used the transferred resources. As a result, the costs of provision of public goods and the cost of government activities generally constitute some transfer of purchasing power by individuals from public goods to the private sector. It is these losses of purchasing power that make every individual a stakeholder in every government decision. These losses also provide a fundamental reason for which individual taxpayers must enter into bargaining and negotiation with the government and among groups that constitute the government bargaining and negotiation are better political science, but on account of resource transfer, there is an economic interface.
The use of derivation as a criterion for revenue allocation is associated with changes in the social state of welfare that results from production activities and the compensation of losers by gainers in production activities. As production takes place in any society, value is created for some members of the society while some members suffer losses due to externalities. A production activity is said to enhance the society’s level of welfare, in Pareto optimality sense, if it is possible for those who gain value (and attain higher welfare level) to compensate those who made losses (and incur a reduction in welfare level) such that the latter is at least left at the level of welfare as before the production with the former group still better off after the redistribution. This principle of redistribution of gains from production in a way that guarantees the removal of welfare losses caused by externalities of production is referred to as compensation principles.
The compensation principle is the basis on which derivation as a criterion for sharing fiscal revenue is anchored. The production of oil, for instance, entails losses to the oil communities in three major ways, namely; natural resources losses – these include the extracted depletable crude petroleum and losses on the vegetative part of the land used in the mining; externalities of oil production – these include environmental pollution, high costs of living, unemployment and loss of means of livelihood due to environmental degradation, etc; social costs of production – for example, breakdown in social value system, high crime, etc. These losses by the oil producing communities due to oil production activities can be compensated for using fiscal means of revenue allocation based on losses suffered by those communities.

THE EVOLUTION OF REVENUE ALLOCATIONS FORMULA TILL 2005


The discovery of oil in some parts of Eastern Nigeria and the potential it had for growth altered the thinking about the place of minerals in the revenue allocation formula. As already mentioned, up till then, royalties from minerals fully belonged to the region of origin. In 1958, however, the discovery of oil in Nigeria coincided with the need to review the existing revenue allocation schemes, which were fallouts of the 1957/58 Constitutional Conference and the imminence of political independence. The colonial government subsequently appointed Sir Jeremy Raisman and Professor Ronald Tress to review the federal fiscal structure. The committee, in the main, recommended that the regions should have authority over produce sales tax and sales tax on motor vehicle fuel. It also recommended the establishment of a Distributable Pool Account (DPA) for the purposes of sharing federally collectible revenues. The commission recommended that the then practice of returning mining rents and royalties to the regions should be discontinued. Such revenues were now to be shared through the DPA with the region of origins getting 50 percent, the federal government, 20 percent and all the other regions, 30 percent. Although oil was a new discovery in the colony, and the revenue from it at the time (1958/59) was estimated to be only 65,000 pounds, it had great prospects. According to the report:

“… The problem is oil. Test production of oil has already started in the Eastern Region and exploration is being undertaken in both the North and the West. While the yield from oil royalties is at present comparatively small, … a double obstacle in our recommending the simple continuation of the existing method of allocating mineral royalties. First, it would involve us, in our revenue assessment for the next few years, in crediting the Eastern Region with a source of income which is at once too uncertain to build upon, and too sizeable to ignore. Secondly, it would rob our recommendations of any confident claim to stability for the future since oil development might take place in any one of the Regions on a scale, which would quite upset the balance of national development, which is part of our task to promote… Our considered conclusion therefore is that the time for change is now, while there is still uncertainty as to which of the Regions may be the lucky beneficiary or which may benefit the most”.

Based on the above, the Raisman Report significantly reduced the use of derivation as a principle for sharing the DPA. In its place, it introduced four variables: continuity, minimum responsibility, population and balanced development of the federation.
As stated above, oil was the first natural resources to be exploited in Nigeria. Prior to its discovery, tin and bauxite were being exploited in the Northern region solely for the benefit of the North. The West could not be bothered because it was the wealthiest of the three regions, thanks to the cocoa boom. The East had very little natural or agricultural resources. Although it was unhappy with the concept of derivation, it was forced to develop other sources of income in its bid to survive.
Technical committee on allocation was then appointed, under the chairmanship of Professor Aboyade. Its propositions were to be submitted to the CDC and if adopted, made part of the new Constitution. In summary, the Committee recommended that all federally collectible revenues, without distinction, should be paid into the federation account. It also, for the first time, took into account, local governments in the vertical distribution of the federation account. It, for instance recommended that the proceeds of the federation account should be shared between the federal government, state governments and local governments in the following proportions: 60 percent, 30 percent and 10 percent respectively. From its share, the federal government was required to set aside 3 percent for the benefit of mineral producing areas and areas in need of rehabilitation from emergencies and disasters.
On the horizontal allocation of revenue amongst the states, the Committee jettisoned the existing principle of revenue sharing arguing that: population has been characterized by illogicality, inconsistency and inequity; derivation had done much to “poison intergovernmental relations and hamper a sense of national unity”; need had “little if any operation relevance”; even development was analytically ambiguous… (and was) not technically feasible to measure in any meaningful way”; equality of status of states was a “consolation prize to states not favoured by the population and derivation principles”; geographical peculiarities defied any “concise definition… (and had) little or no merit”; national interest was “capable of many interpretations (and) circumstances”. It then recommended the adoption of five new principles. These were: equality of access to development opportunities, national minimum standards for national integration, absorptive capacity, independent revenue and tax effort and fiscal efficiency.
The Aboyade Report was however extensively criticized. The economic background of its prescriptions was especially attacked. Sylvester Ugoh, a member of the Constituent Assembly, for instance, questioned the wisdom behind the Reports reliance on its data based on the 1975-1980 National Development Plan. According to him, some sections of the report were based on the implicit assumption that the 1975-80 Plan would be fully or largely implemented. As such, the projects which are represented by these allocations would be realized. In such a situation, what the measure would show would be the socioeconomic gaps that will arise from the full implementation of the Plan. But the fact is that our National Plans, and especially that of 1975-80 Plan has proved to be mostly a national dream. And if that is the situation, how can we use such dream-like allocations, which are unrealistic and unrealizable to measure socioeconomic gaps in our development. Another member of the Constituent Assembly, Dr. Pius Okigbo, criticized the vertical distribution of revenue amongst the various tiers of government arguing that the Aboyade Report unduly favoured the federal government. Based on such criticisms, the Constituent Assembly rejected the Aboyade Report.
In 1979, the newly elected government of President Shehu Shagari appointed a new Committee headed by Dr. Pius Okigbo to review the “formulae for revenue allocation having regard to such factors as the national interest, derivation, population, even development, equitable distribution and the equality of states”. On the sharing of revenue, among the various tiers of government (vertical allocation), the Okigbo Committee recommended the following formulae: federal government (53 percent), state governments (30 percent), local governments (10 percent). 7 percent was to be set aside as special funds for the following purposes: development of the federal capital territory, 2.5 percent; special problems of mineral producing areas, 2 percent; ecological problems, 1 percent; and revenue equalization fund, 1.5 percent. For the horizontal allocation of revenue among the states, the Report adopted four criteria. These were: minimum responsibilities of government (40 percent), population (40 percent), social development factor/primary school enrolment (15 percent) and internal revenue effort (5 percent).
The Government White Paper adopted the Okigbo recommendations only with slight modifications. This culminated in the promulgation of the Revenue Allocation Act No. 1 of 1981. In summary, the Act provided that the federation account shall be shared amongst the various tiers of Government as follows: federal government, 58.5% percent; state governments, 31.5%; local governments, 10%. 26.5 percent of the state allocation shall be allocated to all states, while the remaining 5 percent shall be allocated on the basis of derivation. Two-fifths of the 5 percent of this derivation fund shall be paid out to the states in direct proportion to the value of minerals extracted from their areas while the remaining three-fifths shall be paid into a special fund to be administered by the federal government for the development of the mineral producing areas. The 26.5 percent outstanding to the credit of all states shall be distributed amongst them using the following criteria: equality of states (50 percent), population (40 percent) and land area (10 percent). Finally, the 58.5 percent allocated to the federal government shall be subdivided as follows: responsibilities and duties of the federal government (55 percent), development of the federal capital territory (2.5 percent) and ecological problems (1 percent). This Act was however widely criticized mainly on the grounds that it allocated too much revenue to the federal government to the detriment of the states and local governments. The result was that the federal government could afford to waste valuable resources in the financing of unprofitable white elephant projects while the states and local governments were starved of funds. According to an Editorial by the Daily Sketch at the time: On the vertical distribution of revenue amongst the various tiers of government, for instance, the federal government modified the Okigbo recommendations as follows: federal government 55 percent; state government, 30 percent; local government, 8 percent; and special funds, 7 percent (Government Views on Okigbo Report, 1980:13). To expect an allocation which gives the federal government 55% and the 19 states only 30% to achieve the contrary will be like living in a world of fantasy. There is sufficient evidence to prove that the ugly phenomenon of growth without development arises from the spending of too much money on a few growth industries to the neglect of people-development oriented projects… millions to build giant industries and make our people sub-human? Tens of millions of our people are wallowing in abject poverty. States and local governments whose preeminent jobs are to see to their welfare are helpless. They are starved of funds while the federal government soaked in billions of naira, fritter away much needed money on fruitless and worthless grandiose projects. How human is it to give Abuja 2.5% while even the most populous state cannot get 2%? The average is less than 1.6% for millions of people. This 1981 Act was however, technically declared null and void by the Supreme Court of Nigeria.”

It was subsequently replaced with the Allocation of Revenue (Federation Account) Act No. 1 of 1982. Essentially, this increased the share of the states in the vertical revenue allocation from 31.5 to 35 percent. The FCT was however now classified as a state. Furthermore, the funding for the 1 percent ecological fund was also transferred from the federal government to the states. Finally, the fund for the development of mineral producing areas was reduced from 3 percent to 1.5 percent. The net effect of this was that the federal government’s share of the federation account remained unaltered. On the horizontal sharing of revenue amongst the states, the Decree adopted the following criteria: minimum responsibility of government, 40 percent; population, 40 percent; social development factor, 15 percent; and internal revenue effort, 5 percent.
Shortly after the promulgation of this Act, the military, in December 1983, overthrew the government of Alhaji Shehu Shagari and Major General Mohammadu Buhari became the new Head of State. His government, subsequently, promulgated the Allocation of Revenue (Federation Account) Amendment Decree No. 36 of 1984. This, in the main, only altered the existing formulae for revenue allocation marginally. It reserved 55 percent of the Federation Account exclusively for the federal government and maintained the local governments’ share at 10 percent. The 1 percent and 1.5 percent for the development of mineral producing areas were also retained. The share of the state governments’ in the Federation Account was 32.5 percent. Out of this, 2 percent were to be paid directly to the mineral producing states in direct proportion to the value of minerals extracted from such states. Finally, the Decree retained the Shagari regime basis for the horizontal sharing of revenue amongst the states.
In 1989, the military government then headed by General Ibahim Babangida, appointed a permanent revenue allocation committee: National Revenue Mobilization and Fiscal Commission (NRMAFC). The committee prescribed the following formulae for the horizontal allocation of revenue amongst the states: equality of states, 40 percent; population, 30 percent; internal revenue effort, 20 percent; and, social development factor, 10 percent. The committee also vested the powers to determine the vertical allocation formulae on the National Assembly. The second part of the committee’s recommendations were later adopted and inculcated in the
1989 Constitution. Although some partial democracy took place at the time, it did not last as full military government was restored in 1994 under the leadership of General Sani Abacha. The new government immediately set up a constitutional conference.
Expectedly, the issue of revenue allocation was one of the contentious issues. It has, for instance, been asserted that: in 1994, the mineral producing states at the so-called Constitutional Conference, convened by the federal military government requested that the allocation of revenues derived from their areas be restored to what it was in 1957, namely; 65 percent thereof. Despite numerous discussions at several committee meetings and at plenary session, no agreement was reached. Eventually, it transpired that the powers that be had agreed to allocate 13 percent of the revenues derived from mineral producing areas to the affected state governments. But this was not to be until the proposed new constitution was promulgated in May 1999.
Despite this constitutional provision, the elected civilian government of Chief Olusegun Obasanjo refused to implement it. Instead, it appointed a Committee to review the 1999 Constitution. On the issue of revenue allocation, the Committee recommended that the derivation formulae be increased substantially beyond the 13 percent minimum recommended in the 1999 Constitution. The government again refused to accept this recommendation. Rather, the government asked the Supreme Court to declare that the derivation principle does not apply to offshore oil. The Supreme Court, in its landmark judgement in April 2002 agreed with the position of the federation government. The uproar, especially from some of the affected oil producing states, and the imminence of the April 2003 general elections however made the federal government to cede some grounds to the states on the issue. The legitimacy of such concessions however remains in doubt. This is especially so given the fact that the Supreme Court has already interpreted the constitutional provisions on the matter. It could therefore be argued that only a constitutional amendment can effect a change to the existing position. The revenue allocation debate is therefore likely to continue unless a new system is enthroned which will change the nation’s focus from revenue sharing to revenue generation.

THE CHALLENGES


There are several challenges and contending issues confronting intergovernmental fiscal relations in Nigeria:

1)                       Non – Correspondence Problem


Ideally, each level of government should be given adequate resources to allow it discharge its responsibilities. Because this is not possible, there is usually a lack of correspondence between the spending responsibilities and the tax powers/revenue sources assigned to different levels of government. It is this incongruence that is often referred to as the non-correspondence problem. In Nigeria, most of the major sources of revenue come under the jurisdiction of the federal government yet lower levels of government are supposed to generate internal revenue. There is, therefore, the need to resolve the imbalance between assigned functions and tax powers.
The issues concerning fiscal relations among the constituent units of the Nigerian federation that remain mostly unresolved are the divergence between assigned functions and tax powers, principle of horizontal and vertical revenue allocation, dependence of states and local governments on federal sources of funding, tendency towards concentration and federal presence in the states (Fadahunsi, 1998). The five principles currently applied in the horizontal revenue allocation formula are far from acceptable to all the stakeholders.
Other non-correspondence problems highlighted by the Okpe Union of North America (2005) in their “Towards a renewed federalism in Nigeria” are the notion of unified national wage structure for federal and state civil service, and the educational institutions. To them, drawing copiously from the United States, contend that each federating unit should establish its own salary structure based on its capabilities. In similar challenge, Fadahunsi (1998) challenges the formula for the distribution of the Value Added Tax (VAT) – a direct consumption tax. “What can for instance be the rational basis for the federal government acquisition of 35 percent share of the VAT revenue? Accordingly, it has been suggested that Nigeria should return in principle to the 1960 constitution position on revenue sharing, which recognizes the principle that launching or consuming state ought to be the primary beneficiary of import/consumption activity (but excluding the formula prescribed in Section 135 thereof): that the states within whose territories PMS are consumed shall receive 35 percent of the duty and taxes on such goods or consumption without prejudice to and in addition to what accrues to the state under the existing revenue allocation formula as determined by the National Assembly. To Adawo and Ekong (2003), on vertical formula for VAT, the federal government share should reduced to 10 percent, where the Federal Inland Revenue Service (FIRS) that centrally administers VAT should receive 5 percent, state government 55 percent and local government 30 percent. On horizontal formula for sharing VAT, they suggest the following ratios – equality 40%, financial efficiency 10%, financial responsibility 10%, education and health 10%, derivation 20% and population 10%.

2)    Fiscal Autonomy and Independence


The issue of relative fiscal autonomy and independence of the state and local governments in a true federal structure goes with the corollary issue of the correspondence of governmental functions and revenue sources. Since the creation of the twelve-state structure in 1967, states and local governments have been excessively dependent on the Federation Account. This independence must be reduced if the federating units are to be free to pursue their own development goals without being hampered by the unpredictable fluctuations in their shares of the Federation Account. It is important that revenue sources should be reallocated and made compatible with the fluctuations stated for each tier of government to enhance steady and proper funding of administrative and developmental activities instead of the often experienced unexpected financial constrictions at the two lower tiers of government.

3)                 Oil Producing States, Oil Producing Local Government Administrative Areas or Communities 


Professor Omo Omoruyi in his treatise “the Politics of Oil: who owns the oil, Nigeria, states or communities” (2000) raised three salient questions on true ownership of oil in Nigeria. The question of local control over local resources is an established constitutional principle in federal systems. But the way the Nigerian federal system developed under the external colonial order (1954-60) and continued under the period of geo-ethno-military internal colonial order (1960-1999) and in the democratic dispensation between 1999 to date is yet an unresolved contending issues in the discourse about Nigeria’s federalism. He challenged the “Tripod” approach to Nigeria’s problem where the three major ethnic nationalities decide the content and the trend of national issues. “This tripod approach to Nigerian politics, should have been done away with by now, with the introduction of the notion of ‘federal character’, which takes states in the federation as the units of representation. The tripod approach to Nigerian politics also applies to how the oil, which comes from the non-majority areas, is approached in the political and economic discourse. We should also be aware of the feeling among the majority ethnic nationalities that the areas producing oil by virtue of powerlessness in the military and politics should not be allowed to lay claim to the oil from their areas as of right”.
However, Professor Omoruyi drew a distinction between oil producing communities and oil producing states. This is the basis of the activities of the Traditional Rulers of the Producing Communities who are dealing with the President and want the money due to states on the basis of the 13% derivation in the Constitution should be paid to the “oil producing communities/local government areas”. The Traditional Rulers’ argument is that “communities” own oil and not “states”. This is an unresolved issue and separates the communities in riverside areas directly affected by oil spillages from their compatriots in landed areas from enjoying the full benefits of allocations to producing states. One does not know the end of this argument. How should the National Assembly address this matter? The federal government should find a way of making the oil producing local government administrative areas as shareholders in the joint venture arrangements with the oil companies, thus making them stakeholders in the oil industry. 
There was the issue of who should be spending the oil money. Should it be the Nigerian government in conjunction with the oil producing areas? Should it be the oil producing areas alone? The Constitution from 1960 till after the civil war up till 1978 gave the right of ownership to the federal government but the proceeds were shared between the federal government and the regions or states on the basis of derivation like the agricultural crops. Professor Omoruyi (2000) further averred, “for the avoidance of doubt, the ownership question was clearly spelt out in the 1979 Constitution and in subsequent enactments. From the 1979 Constitution, any claim of the right of ownership of minerals was denied the units in the federation called states. This rule also denies the right of ownership to local communities. We need to ask the extent to which this portends any solution to the Niger Delta crisis and its implication for a constitutional amendment.

4)             Federation Account and the Derivation Fund


It is important to define what constitutes the Federation Account – to which the various vertical revenue allocation formulae have been applied and what should be directly financed from it. Up to 1990, the amount accruing yearly to the Federation Account was still over 96% of totally federally collected revenue; but since 1991, when it first dropped to about 75% and nose-dived to around 35% by 1997, it showed no sign of recovery (Olowononi, 1999). It is therefore clear, that in such a situation, whatever the vertical formula applicable, there must still be a serious fiscal imbalance between the federal government and the two lower tiers of government. It is crucial to redress this revenue imbalance in the spirit of balanced true federalism. What appears to account for this imbalance is the assertion of the self-claimed right by the federal government to finance various first-line charges from the Federation Account before the application of the vertical formula. The first-line charges include funding for external debt service, national priority projects, NNPC priority projects, special reserve account, and excess proceeds of the crude oil sales account, and in addition, the joint venture cash calls account. These deductions are made from the proceeds of crude oil sales before the derivation fund in the Federation Account is arrived at, and after which further deductions for special funds and the funding of the federal capital territory are made. It will seem more logical, with the exception of the joint venture case calls, that these various charges which are federal government obligations be financed solely from the federal government’s revenue proper, that is, from its share of the Federation Account or from its revenue from other sources. Therefore, in order to determine what constitutes the derivation fund, resolving the issue of the Federation Account is crucial. Thereafter, the derivation formula to be utilized can be arrived at.

5)             Oil – Producing Areas and the Derivation Principle


The crude oil production has been the most important economic activity in the Nigerian economy since the early 1970s is not subject to debate. Its impact is not limited to its contributing almost 90% of Nigeria’s total foreign exchange earnings but also to the fact that the national budgets are predicated on the expected annual production and price of crude oil. Thus, crude oil is the primary engine for national economic growth and development. It is, therefore, quite reasonable to expect that the areas producing the nation’s crude oil would be very highly developed as compensation for what is taken away as well as for the devastation on the land engendered by the exploration process. There should have been development of physical and social infrastructures, human capital creation, and economic empowerment of the general citizenry in those areas.
The Niger Delta area suffers near total neglect by both the federal government, which claims ownership of the oil, and the multinational companies, which actually exploits the oil reserves. It is a picture of wanton environmental degradation of all types – land (despoliation of farmlands), water (destruction of fishing areas and sources of drinking water), and air (release of many pollutants causing diseases in humans, animals and plants). The people in the Niger Delta states who hitherto were able to cater for their needs are now being confronted with poverty through loss of their means of livelihood. The intervention of the federal government through the Niger Delta Development Commission (NDDC) seems to be a welcome development. However, the missing factor seems to be the proper treatment of the derivation principle in a way that would enable the state and local governments of the oil producing areas to handle their developmental problems according to their own felt needs and priorities. The minimization of the derivation factor over the years – from the earlier 50% to 1% and now 13%, only as it affects crude oil – is unjust and unfair when one considers that Igbeti Marble attract 55% derivation and the Value Added Tax (VAT) still attracts 20% derivation. The challenge will be to reexamine the issue of derivation particularly in line with the new democratic experiment.

6)                      Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations and the Economy


It is expected that fiscal decentralization would stimulate growth and development. There is the need to ascertain whether this has taken place in the country particularly as large amount of resources have been transferred from the center to both State and Local Governments.
The latest of several official and unofficial constitution reform initiatives, the NPRC is charged with forging a national consensus on new constitutional blueprint for “reinforcing the unity, cohesion, stability, security, progress, development and performance of the Nigerian federation” (Obasanjo, 2005:72). Yet, halfway into its proposed four-month tenure, the NPRC is already embroiled in the contradictions and divisions often associated with the politics of mega-constitutional change in deeply divided societies. Especially palpable is the increasing polarization of the Conference along a geopolitical fault-line that pits putative southern Nigerian constitutional reformers against more pragmatic northern conservatives.

SUMMARY AND CONCLUSION


Fiscal federalism refers to the scope and structure of the tiers of government responsibilities and functions as well as the allocation of resources among the tiers of government. Contemporary issues in Nigeria’s political economy show that perhaps the most important issue of fiscal federalism is the revenue allocation formula, the sharing of national revenue among the various tiers of government (vertical revenue sharing) as well as the distribution of revenue among the state governments (that is, horizontal revenue allocation). In Nigeria, decisions as to what proportion of centrally-generated revenue that would be retained by the federal government, the proportion that will be shared among the state governments and the proportion that will go to the local government has always been a problem, due to the fact that there is no consensus of opinion as to what could be seen as an ideal formula. 
Since the 1946 Richardson Constitution which granted internal autonomy to the thenexisting three regions, there have been several attempts to provide equitable revenue allocation formula consistent with the sharing of responsibilities between the federal and regional/state governments. The most recent development in the struggle for the control of oil resources in Nigeria is the recent Supreme Court action instituted by the federal government against the oil producing states with respect to the offshore/onshore oil dichotomy. The April 2002 decision of the Supreme Court to exclude the revenue derived from offshore drilling the calculation of the revenue attributable to the oil producing states based on the derivation principle, has failed to resolve the controversy.
There are several challenges and contending issues confronting intergovernmental fiscal relations in Nigeria: The five principles currently applied in the horizontal revenue allocation formula are far from acceptable to all the stakeholders. There is usually a lack of correspondence between the spending responsibilities and the tax powers/revenue sources assigned to different levels of government. There is, therefore, the need to resolve the imbalance between assigned functions and tax powers.
On the issue of relative fiscal autonomy and independence of the states and local governments, this dependence of sub-national units of government must be reduced if the federating units are to be free to pursue their own development goals without being hampered by the unpredictable fluctuations in their shares of the Federation Account.
The question of local control over local resources is an established constitutional principle in federal systems. But the way the Nigerian federal system developed under the external colonial order (1954-60) and continued under the period of geo-ethno-military internal colonial order (1960-1999) and in the democratic dispensation between 1999 to date is yet an unresolved contending issues in the discourse about Nigeria’s federalism.
Do we need to constitutionally recognize a distinction between oil producing communities and oil producing states? This is an unresolved issue and separates the communities in riverside areas directly affected by oil spillages from their compatriots in landed areas from enjoying the full benefits of allocations to producing states. Also, the federal government should find a way of making the oil producing local government administrative areas as shareholders in the joint venture arrangements with the oil companies, thus making them stakeholders in the oil industry. It is expected that the areas producing the nation’s crude oil would be very highly developed as compensation for what is taken away as well as for the devastation on the land engendered by the exploration process. There should have been development of physical and social infrastructures, human capital creation, and economic empowerment of the general citizenry in those areas. The missing factor seems to be the proper treatment of the derivation principle in a way that would enable the States and local governments of the oil producing areas to handle their developmental problems according to their own felt needs and priorities. What solutions can be deduced for the problems emanating from the challenge of the “Tripod” approach to Nigeria’s problems where the three major ethnic nationalities decide the content and the trend of national issues?
There is the issue of deductions that are made from the proceeds of crude oil sales before the derivation fund in the Federation Account is arrived at, and after which further deductions for special funds and the funding of the federal capital territory are made. It will seem more logical, with the exception of joint venture cash calls, that these various charges which are federal government obligations be financed solely from the federal government’s revenue power, that is, from its share of the Federation Account or from its share revenue from other sources. Therefore, in order to determine what constitutes the derivation fund, resolving the issue of the Federation Account is crucial.

REFERENCES


Adawo, M. A. and Ekong, C. N. (2003) “The Place of Value Added Tax (VAT) in Revenue Allocation” in Ekpo, Akpan H. and Ubok-Udom, Enamidem (ed.) (2003) Issues in Fiscal Federalism and Revenue Allocation in Nigeria, Uyo: University of Uyo, pp.199-229.
Agbu, Osita (2004) “Re-inventing Federalism in Post-Transition Nigeria: Problems and Prospects”. African Development, Vol. XXIX, No. 2, 2004, pp.26-52.
Akpan Godwin and Umodong, Enobong (2003) “Majority Rule over Minority Right: Subversion of Derivation Criterion in Revenue Allocation in Nigeria” in Ekpo, Akpan H. and Ubok-Udom, Enamidem (ed.) (2003) Issues in Fiscal Federalism and Revenue Allocation in Nigeria, Uyo: University of Uyo, pp.335-375.
Akpakpan, Edet B. (2003) “The Economics of Revenue Allocation in Nigeria”, in Ekpo, Akpan H. and Ubok-Udom, Enamidem (ed.) (2003) Issues in Fiscal Federalism and Revenue Allocation in Nigeria, Uyo: University of Uyo, pp.12-24.
Aluko, Mobalaji (2005) “The Latest Revenue Allocation Formula in Nigeria – A Quick Inspection” www.nigeriavillagesquare.com
Anugwom, Edlyne E. (2001) “Federalism, Fiscal Centralism and the Realities of Democratization in Nigeria: The Case of the Niger Delta” in UNESCO/ENA, 2001 Africa at Crossroads: Complex Political Emergencies in the 21st Century.
Egwaikhide, Festus and Ekpo, Akpan (2000) “The Politics of Revenue Allocation in Nigeria” in in Ekpo, Akpan H. and Ubok-Udom, Enamidem (ed.) (2003) Issues in Fiscal Federalism and Revenue Allocation in Nigeria, Uyo: University of Uyo, pp.25-46.
Ehwarieme, W. (1999) The Military: Oil and Development: the Political Economic of Fiscal Federalism in Nigeria, in Fiscal Federalism and Nigeria’s Economic Development (Ibadan, Nigerian Economic Society).
Ekpo, Akpan H. “Intergovernmental Fiscal Relations: The Nigerian Experience”. Paper Presented at the 10th Year Anniversary of The Financial and Fiscal Commission of South Africa, Cape Town International Convention Centre, Cape Town, South Africa, 10-12 August 2004.
Eminue, Okon (2003) Revenue Allocation among Federal, State and Local Governments (1990 – 1998) in Ekpo, Akpan H. and Ubok-Udom, Enamidem (ed.) (2003) Issues in Fiscal Federalism and Revenue Allocation in Nigeria, Uyo: University of Uyo, pp.140-163.
Fadahunsi, Akin (1998) “The Nigerian Nationalities and Fiscal Federalism”. Paper presented at a Seminar on “Devolution of Power in a Federal State” organized by Friedrich Ebert Foundation, University of Lagos, October.
Iniodu, P. U. and Archibong, P. E. (2003) “Revenue Allocation among State and Local
Governments” in Ekpo, Akpan H. and Ubok-Udom, Enamidem (ed.) (2003) Issues
in Fiscal Federalism and Revenue Allocation in Nigeria, Uyo: University of Uyo, pp.164-198.
Musgrave, R. A. and P. B. Musgrave (1982) Public Finance in Theory and Practice. New York: McGraw Hill Book Company.
Natufe, Omajuwa (2005) Okpe Union of North America: Towards a Renewed Federalism in Nigeria. Accessed from the Internet.
Nyong, M. O. (1998) Fiscal Federation, Revenue Allocation Formula and Economic Development in Nigeria. Nigeria Financial Review, Vol. 7, No. 3, pp.33-54. 
Nyong, Michael (2003) “Fiscal Federalism, Revenue Allocation Formula and Economic Development in Nigeria”, in Ekpo, Akpan H. and Ubok-Udom, Enamidem (ed.) (2003) Issues in Fiscal Federalism and Revenue Allocation in Nigeria, Uyo: University of Uyo, pp.407-445.
Obi, C. (1998) The Impact of Oil and Nigeria’s Revenue Allocation System: Problems and Prospects for National Reconstruction, in Amuwo, K., Agbaje, A., Suberu, R. and Herault, G. (eds) Federalism and Political Restructuring in Nigeria (Ibadan: Spectrum Books Limited).
Olukoshi, Adebayo and Osita Agbu (1995) “The Deepening Crisis of Nigerian Federalism and the Future of the Nation-State”, in Liisa Laakso and A. Olukoshi (eds) Challenges to the Nation-State in Africa, Uppsala, the Nordic Africa Institute.
Uche, Chibuike U. and Ogbonnaya Uche (2004) “Oil and the Politics of Revenue Allocation in Nigeria”. African Studies Centre, Lieden Netherlands, ASC Working Paper 54/2004.
Wantchekony, Leonard (1999) “Why do Resource Dependent Countries have Authoritarian Governments?” Yale University Accessed.

No comments:

Post a Comment